You are looking for factors
Learn how discreet factors are gradually rewriting the rules of risk and reward
Table of contents:
Introduction.
What is a factor?
Factors as building blocks of systems.
Predictive versus explanatory modeling.
Risk Factors, sparse conditions, and systematic alpha generation.
Introduction
The story of factor investing isnโt just a tale of numbers and modelsโitโs a revolution sparked in the hallowed halls of academia. Picture this: Itโs the mid-20th century, and economists are on the hunt for the DNA of market success. Enter Eugene Fama and Kenneth French , two intellectual titans whose groundbreaking research didnโt just crack the code of stock returnsโit rewrote it.
Fama, the University of Chicago maestro behind the Efficient Market Hypothesis, teamed up with French to dissect what really drives investment performance. Their discoveries? A set of factors acting as financial superpowers: market risk, size, value and momentum. Together, these factors formed the Fama-French model:
where:
Riโ is the return of asset iii,
Rfโ is the risk-free rate,
ฮฑiโ is the assetโs alpha,
ฮฒi,1,ฮฒii,2,ฮฒii,3,โ are factor loadings, and
ฯตiโ is the idiosyncratic error term.
It was a golden age and although things have changed a lot, quantitative research should be closer to the factors than to anything else.
What is a factor?
Letโs get mathematical. A factor is defined as a variable X that explains a portion of the variability in asset returns Y. The relationship is often assumed to be linear, so we model it as:
where:
Y is the asset return,
ฮฒ is the sensitivity of the asset return to the factor X,
ฯต is the noise term.
In an ideal world, ฯต would be zero, but then weโd have a market as predictable as my morning coffee routineโand we all know markets are much messier than that!
But what information do you use as X? Well, there are all kinds of resources. The most common ones are:
Depending on what you choose your system will produce different types of returns and risk profiles:

There are more. But personally I prefer high volatility factors, you will understand ahead the reason.
For the moment, the question here is: why are they so important? Factors are not just theoretical constructsโthey serve as the bedrock of decision-making algorithms. But why is that!? To answer this we need to consider two key pillars:
Teleological relationships.
Causality.
Teleological relationships answer the if X then Y question. Suppose we have a factor Xโsay, momentumโand asset return Y. The causal hypothesis might be stated as:
But in real markets, causality is rarely so simple. Sometimes the relationship is spuriousโlike believing that wearing a lucky tie makes your portfolio soar. We formalize causality with the concept of conditional expectation:
where E[YโฃX] is the expected return given factor X. The challenge for quants is to differentiate between correlation and causation, and to do so with the precision of a laser-guided algorithm!
Now that weโve warmed up with some equations, letโs journey into the factor-based approach, where the initial excitement of a novel factor quickly fades as the market catches on.
Factors as building blocks of systems
The basic building block is a factor X that informs the decision. Consider a simple strategy: if X exceeds a threshold ฮธ, we buy; otherwise, we sell.
Mathematically, the signal S can be represented as:
The return R on the strategy might then be modeled as:
where Rj is the risk-free rate. In other words, if our factor signals buy when returns exceed the risk-free rate, we profit. But when everyone uses the same X, the signal becomes as popular as a cat video on the internetโeveryoneโs watching, and nothingโs new.
This could be an example of the desirable factor:
Pretty sure, huh? You'll get paid a lot of money if you find something like that.
By the way, another important issue here is factor crowding. It occurs when many market participants trade based on the same signal X. This is mathematically problematic because as more traders join the party, the effective signal strength weakens. We can describe the dilution of the factorโs effect with a crowding coefficient ฮณ, where 0โคฮณโค10:
with ฮณ decreasing as the number of participants increases. For example, if ฮณ=0.5, the impact of X on returns is halved compared to a less crowded market.
A neat mathematical model for crowding might look like:
where N is the number of participants and ฮป is a sensitivity parameter. When N is large, ฮณ tends to zero, implying that our once-spicy factor is now as bland as unsalted oatmeal.